翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ The Death of Adonis (Rubens)
・ The Death of an Insect
・ The Death of Art
・ The Death of Artemio Cruz
・ The Death of Bees
・ The Death of Bessie Smith
・ The Death of Black King
・ The Death of Britain?
・ The Death of Buffy
・ The Death of Bunny Munro
・ The Death of Captain America
・ The Death of Captain James Cook (Zoffany)
・ The Death of Celebrity
・ The Death of Chatterton
・ The Death of Cleopatra
The Death of Contract
・ The Death of Cool
・ The Death of Cool (Huffamoose album)
・ The Death of Digenis
・ The Death of Economics
・ The Death of Emmett Till
・ The Death of Empedocles
・ The Death of Empedocles (film)
・ The Death of Eric Cartman
・ The Death of Ferro Lad
・ The Death of Frequent Flyer
・ The Death of General Warren at the Battle of Bunker's Hill, June 17, 1775
・ The Death of General Wolfe
・ The Death of God
・ The Death of God (song)


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

The Death of Contract : ウィキペディア英語版
The Death of Contract

''The Death of Contract'' is a book by American law professor Grant Gilmore, written in 1974, about the history and development of the common law of contracts.〔Gilmore, Grant. ''The Death of Contract''. The Ohio State University Press, 1974, 2nd edition 1995. ISBN 0-8142-0676-X〕〔(Comments on The Death of Contract, from Ohio State University Press )〕 Gilmore's central thesis was that the Law of Contracts, at least as it existed in the 20th-century United States was largely artificial: it was the work of a handful of scholars and judges building a system, rather than a more organic, historically rooted development based on the evolution of case law. This book is required supplemental reading in the first year program at many U.S. law schools. A second edition was published in 1995, which was edited with a new introduction by Ronald K.L. Collins.
== Chapter 1. Origin ==
Gilmore begins the introduction forcefully, stating "We are told that Contract, like God, is dead. And so it is." Gilmore then brings us through the life of Contract, from birth to death. He notes that courts had been deciding contract law for centuries before the theory of contracts was introduced by Christopher Columbus Langdell. This assertion, that Langdell "invented" the general theory of contracts is somewhat contested by contracts scholars, with Richard Austen-Baker, for example, pointing out the lack of any evidence of any theory of contract authored by Langdell, to prior work by English jurists such as Addison and Leake and to far more developed work by English scholars such as Sir William Anson and Sir Frederick Pollock, contemporary with Langdell.〔R. Austen-Baker "Gilmore and the Strange Case of the Failure of Contract to Die After All" (2002) 18 ''Journal of Contract Law'' 1.〕
Gilmore retains the central idea that the general law of contract is a residual category, that is, what is left after all the specialized bodies of law have been added up. The world of commercial law, and within it contract law, was largely the product of the Industrial Revolution. It was created quite rapidly, outlined in little more than a half-century. Initially, for legal greats like Justice Story, there was no separate theory of contracts. Rather, there were specialized bodies of law that had been developed to address the various needs of the Industrial Revolution. Gilmore alleges, that rather than contract coming first, and the various specialties being developed afterwards, it actually was the opposite, where contract enveloped pre-existing specialties, like negotiable instruments and sales.
Gilmore credits Langdell with the “almost inadvertent discovery” of contract law, as it was the subject of his very first casebook. The goal of Langdell’s casebook was to reduce the world of contracts to major underlying principles in a scientific fashion. The theory of contracts created by Langdell is furthered by Oliver Wendell Holmes, Jr. and Samuel Williston, which Gilmore calls the Holmes-Williston construct. The theory is described whereby, “no one should be liable to anyone for anything.”, or at least liability shall be strictly limited. Damages in contract were distinguished from damages in tort, and punitive damages were not to be allowed. Furthermore, courts were to act as “detached umpires or referees” and only to see that the rules of the game were followed, but not to “see that justice or anything of that sort was done.” Gilmore further describes Holmes’ view on objective interpretation of contract law, as laid out in ''The Common Law''. Thus, Gilmore states that the theory of contracts was not developed naturally from continual case law development, such as the decisions by Lord Mansfield,〔See ''Hawkes v Saunders'' (1782) 98 ER 1091 and ''Pillans v Van Mierop'' (1765) 97 ER 1035. He notes that ''Eastwood v Kenyon'' (1840) 114 ER 482 is typically seen as the final rejection of Lord Mansfield's ideas.〕 but rather it was an “ivory tower abstraction” that lived “in the law schools, not the law courts.” Often the rules of contract were the result of a string of cases being pulled together, with little citation or presentation of the facts, and declared to be a rule in the works of Williston. The problem with contract theory was that “businessman, adapting to changing circumstance, kept doing things differently. The general theory required that, always and everywhere, things remain as they have, in theory, always been.” He illustrates this argument by reference to English case law that had been elevated by the theorists to the status of "rules", in ''Stilk v Myrick'', ''Dickinson v Dodds'' and ''Foakes v Beer'', all as a way of ensuring that the doctrine of consideration would preclude the enforceability of a contract.

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「The Death of Contract」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.